| |
THE
STRUCTURE OF ISLAMIC ECONOMICS: A COMPARATIVE
PERSPECTIVE ON MARKETS, ETHICS AND ECONOMICS
Dr
Masudul Alam Choudhury
Abstract
A comparative examination of mainstream economic doctrines and their
recent developments is undertaken with a view to find out how ethics has
been treated in these. The principal focus here is to identify the new
paradigm that can treat ethics endogenously in preference formation, the
market and the economic order. The quest for this paradigm leads us to an
examination of Islamic economics. Islamic economics is presented in terms
of its epistemological roots. Thereby, a general systems view of
interactions, integration and creative evolution among economic and social
possibilities is shown to lead to the paradigm of Islamic political
economy. Some Islamic financial and economic instruments are examined to
bring out the pervasive causality of the principle of universal
complementarity across diversity in a general systems perspective of
Islamic political economy as premised on its epistemological roots.
Our principal
objective in this paper is to place Islamic economic thinking in a
distinctive paradigm of its own in comparative perspective of economic
theory as it has evolved and indeed as Islamic economics itself has
evolved. Thus we will take a critical examination of these alternative
premises of economic thinking while laying down the epistemological
foundation of the worldview of human inquiry in Islam. Within this world
view can be discoursed economic, social and scientific issues and
problems. We will then explain some usually known Islamic economic and
financial instruments within the paradigmatic worldview that we will
establish on epistemological grounds.
In occidental history of economic thought there were two major
path-breaking revolutions, classicism and Keynesianism. Although many
other ones can be taken up within these major classes of thinking, we will
devote to the parent ones only. We will also see that the search for new
thinking in economics in recent times has once again found itself gripped
in one or the other of these schools or a combination of the two.
The First Revolution in Economic
Thought: The Classical Economic School
Classical Economic Orthodoxy: Adam Smith
The classical economic
school gave a scientific theory of market capitalism. Yet classicism
was more than a mere study of egoistic behaviour of self-interested
individuals in a market venue. Rather, Adam Smith’s Wealth of
Nations is a compendium of social and economic issues in which
institutions and governments are seen to play distinct roles in
attaining efficient organization of markets. Yet the kind of
orientation given to public organization in the midst of
self-interest, and in this way, the method of externalizing social
values through institutions and governments, assume a particular
form in this first great revolutionary and monumental work. We will
explain this now.
Smith’s first work, The Theory of Moral Sentiments received greater
attention during his life than the Wealth of Nations. The latter
work became prominent only posthumously. In Moral Sentiments Smith
saw human sympathy to be emerging from the springs of natural
liberty. The principles of natural liberty respecting human liberty
and happiness were made to premise individual, social and
institutional aspirations. In methodologically explaining such
preferences, Smith wanted to see scientific laws of natural liberty
become its part and parcel. Thereafter, institutions became
representation of such individual preferences if they were founded
on sympathy, ethical behaviour and just exchange for benefiting from
the various possibilities that the human order can bestow. Thereby,
within such a scientific system endowed by its equilibrium and
optimal principles of natural liberty, goods and services comprised
not simply purely economic ones but also moral and ethical ones.
Today John Rawls calls social and ethical market values to be
‘primaries’ (Rawls
1971). In
this sense, Smith emulated Aristotle’s economic thinking in terms of
ethical perfection, which the latter wanted to utilize as the
attributes of a good society with wealth and politics in it. These
points are brought out eloquently in Aristotle’s Nichomachean Ethics
(Welldon
1987,
Barker
1959). Smith was also like Kant in his moral prerogatives. Kant
found epistemological questions of history, society, economy and
politics to be embedded in what he called as the universal law of
history (Reiss
1970).
But like Aristotle, Smith’s institutions and government were a
lateral aggregation of perfect individuals all transformed by a
vision of natural liberty in the quest for freedom and happiness
characterizing the human order. Institutions just as individuals
were thereby, assumed to be capable of attaining the optimal and
equilibrium levels of freedom and happiness. The market order
characterized by exchange of atomistic individuals then became a
necessity for institution to realize this kind of free and
non-interventionist attainment of freedom and happiness.
The natural liberty principle of Moral Sentiments thus led to the
emergence of the markets of Wealth of Nations. These were made up of
self-interested, optimal and equilibrium modes of exchange and
agency under such an atomistic market assumption. Consequently, we
find that in such an aggregation of individual preferences toward
forming institutional preferences all of economic analysis became an
academic venture in optimal allocation of resources. The high moral,
ethical and social values earlier conceived by Smith in his Moral
Sentiments got washed away in his Wealth of Nations, wherein market
exchange and the role of institutions and governments in this order
became the prime sway (Coase
1994).
In the assumed state of optimality and equilibrium allocation of
scarce resources among exchangeables, the agents had to become
independent of each other, not interactive ones. In this way, the
exchange mechanism was invisibly premised on the exchange of
atomistic agency, which by selling small and being small while being
many, could not explain a process of evolution of market exchange
within a scientific paradigm of markets and ethics. In other words,
while optimality and equilibrium of resource allocation were assumed
to exist, yet it was not known how such an optimum and equilibrium
state was attainable through a social process (Shackle
1971). A process is understood here to mean a continuous system of
interactions, convergence and re-emergence through a vast nexus of
cause and effects (Whitehead
1979).
In the post-hoc optimal state there cannot exist any sharing
possibility between agents, variables and sub-systems (e.g.
markets). Hence the possibility of interactions disappears in the
long-run optimal state of resource allocation. Agents were assumed
to have already conceded at every point of the resource allocation
trajectory to consistent optimal and equilibrium states. This is the
focus of economic analysis in the classical school. The
representation of aggregate preferences of individuals and groups in
institution making became stronger in the theory of civil
libertarianism propounded by Bentham. From this background the
occidental world inherited the idea of utilitarianism, that is
sum-ranking and interpersonal comparison of utilities (Bentham
1789,
Harsanyi
1955,
Hammond
1987).
Thus in the first revolution in economic and social thinking we find
its focus to have been on a scientific explanation of human action
in accordance with the principle of natural liberty. But this very
scientific approach led to a design of the market order,
institutional order and social systems that got premised on
optimality, equilibrium and individualism. Consequently, no
substantive understanding of social interactions could be offered in
explaining the passage towards a final equilibrium and optimal state
of viable socioeconomic variables. When individuals lost their
capacity to discourse even as they attained their assumed optimal
and equilibrium states of happiness and freedom, they also lost the
capacity of being ethically active. Ethics and markets thus got
dissociated. Ethics became exogenous to economics and market
function.
Neo-Classicism
In the neo-classical
economic school that followed the works of Walras, Jevons and
Marshall, the classical economic ideas were perpetuated on the
demand side of markets. Earlier, the classical economic school had
focused on the supply side. Neo-classicism further entrenched the
theory of self-interested preference behaviour of individuals into a
theory of social optimum and equilibrium, albeit introducing such
preferences into a systems view of multi-markets.
Preferences in turn were treated as the origin of economic value in
relation to relative prices. Relative prices of the neo-classical
school explaining economic choice, and absolute prices of the
classical school representing economic value had to be empirically
observed. Hence all goods and services had to be measured. Even when
numinous social goods and services entered exchange, they had to be
treated within the purview of measurement in order to be considered
in economic analysis. Encompassing these constrictions were the
axioms of rational economic behaviour of agents, full or bounded
information (hence bounded rationality), and measurable probability
of uncertain events. This convenience was essentially required for
determining the structure and bounds of a reductionist economic
space. Reductionism is not even limited to economics in such
doctrines. It is found inherent in the sciences as a whole. Against
this constricted view of science Dampier has written his incisive
critique (Dampier
1961). Such a priori needs for boundedness to attain assumed states
of optimality and equilibrium remained structurally invariant over
time in the economic space. As a consequence of assumed predictive
nature of economic reasoning, time in it becomes non-substantive in
neo-classical economic theory (Robinson
1965, 1973). Prediction remains structurally unchanging as a
prescribed human behaviour, irrespective of time-dependent change of
the economic variables.
Institutions now are once again structurally embedded in the lateral
aggregation of independent, optimal and equilibrium preferences as
manifested by the utilitarian doctrine. Such a society-wide
behavioural assumption in neo-classical thought is termed as
methodological individualism. Because of such logical continuity of
neo-classicism to classicism we will not treat this school as a
distinct revolution in economic thought.
Neo-classical economic school introduced the method of marginalism
to treat resource allocation among competing ends under scarcity.
But in doing so they turned such allocation points into axiomatic
long-run optimal and equilirbium points. Consequently, marginalism
became a powerful method that intrinsically stayed in neo-classicism
and gave it the abiding structural character of a non-interactive
worldview. Marginalism thus explains non-interaction and relates
this state to optimality, scarcity, and equilibrium in the long-run.
By thus making individuals and institutions choose in the absence of
systemic learning at the marginal points of resource allocation, the
method of marginalism intensified the view of methodological
individualism in neo-classical economic behaviour (Parson
1964).
Marx Briefly
For similar reasons,
since Marx was an exponent of the classical economic school albeit
with a much wider agenda of social interactions, we will subsume
Marxism within classical economics. Yet it must be mentioned in the
context of the theme of this paper that the great debility of
Marxism despite its attempt to explain social interactions arose
from Marx’s silent negation of markets and3 his duality of prices
and values in the economic system (Mandell
1971,Ghosh
&
Choudhury
1997). Such dualism replaced the meaning of market exchange by
institutional re-organization, principally of production rather than
of consumption (Martinez
1990). In this, economic planning subsumed the market function.
Historicism rather than praxis (von
Mises 1976),
which has its roots in markets and ethics, was made the explainer of
economic change. Contrarily, as von Mises wrote (1960): "Theory as
distinct from history is the search for constant relations between
entities or, what means the same, for regularity in the succession
of events. In establishing epistemology as a theory of knowledge,
the philosopher implicitly assumes or asserts that there is in the
intellectual effort of man something that remains unchanged, viz.
the logical structure of the human mind."
|
The Second Revolution in Economic Thought: The
Keynesian School
The Economic Orthodoxy of John Maynard Keynes
The second great
revolution in economic thought was by John Maynard Keynes. His General
Theory of Employment, Interest and Money bequeathed to academia a
different way of looking at the aggregate economic universe.
Aggregation was not derived from the notion of sum-ranking of
individual preferences at the institutional level. Likewise, markets
do not exist in Keynesian analysis. It is only that aggregate market
effects are analyzed at the institutional level. There are no
decision-makers; even government is not a decision-maker in Keynesian
analysis. It is only that the economy-wide effects of decision-making
taken elsewhere, are analyzed aggregatively. Consequently, Keynes gave
an idea of economic and social aggregation different from its
classical and neo-classical meaning.
Instead, in Keynesian economics aggregation of economic variables and
activities is associated with large institutions that already find
their place in society and economy for protecting the interest of
citizens in democratic and free-market capitalism. Consequently, while
to the utilitarians Government is a representation of aggregate
preferences of optimal individuals and is in turn charged to look
after and promote the same preferences, to Keynes the idea of
Government in economic analysis is an institution entrusted to
safe-guard the national economy. General Theory thus marked a new way
of conceptualizing a general system of equilibrium interrelationships
and analysis within this framework for the common good.
Keynes was thus a deep epistemologist like Smith in developing this
paradigm of aggregate and systemic view of social relations (O’Donell
1989). However, even in this structure of economic and social thought
and despite the fact that Keynes like Smith was moved by the central
role of ethics in economic matters, he was unable to explain a value
system in his economic analysis. Problems arise due to the absence of
decision-makers in Keynesian aggregate economics. Likewise, Keynes’
general equilibrium analysis being premised on the explanation of
systemic causality among large institutions in key sectors, is not
centered on the explanation of visibly human interactions. Thus once
again, like the classical and neo-classical economic schools,
Keynesian general equilibrium had to be attained on the assumption
that economic equilibria exist conjointly in four principal sectors of
the economy with or without economic policy impact. These sectors are
the product market, the labour market, the money market and the
expenditure sector. The expenditure sector is simply the result of the
other three sectors.
When Keynes considered economic policy in his general equilibrium
framework for these sectors, he launched a new idea beyond the stable
equilibrium concept of the neo-classicists. Keynes thought of an
inevitable existence of under-employment equilibrium and downward
inflexible price levels even in the best performing capitalist
economy. He then set to improve such an under-employment to full
employment by activating national output. Economic entropy and its
correction is thereby inherent in Keynes’ vision of the social and
economic universe. Consequently, principal policy variables, such as,
government expenditure (fiscal policy) and monetary policy for
attaining full-employment equilibrium were meant to improve the state
of the economy by improving the equilibria in the four sectors, to a
full-employment output level beyond under-employment equilibrium.
Price stabilization was not a pre-occupation of Keynes, for
full-employment was attainable in his general equilibrium system by a
mobilization of under-utilized resources into productive ventures
using fiscal and monetary policies (other policies can be tied to
these). It was then these productive ventures that subsequently
generated the income multiplier for attaining full-employment output.
Full employment, government expenditure for social economic
stimulation, productive investments, need for low interest rates,
economic policies and the general equilibrium framework based on these
conditions, were essential elements of Keynes’ ethico-economics.
Keynes as an ethicist wrote in his Essays on Persuasion (1930): : A
somewhat disgusting morbidity, one of those semi-criminal,
semi-pathological propensities which one hands down over with a
shudder to the specialists in mental disease."
What then was the flaw in the aggregate economics (macroeconomics)
with respect to Keynes’ ethical epistemology in economics? The absence
of ethical perceptors (preferences) needed to perform the ethical acts
created the ethical dysfunction. Consequently, there was no human
discourse and hence no interaction toward explaining a systemic
process. We referred to this problem earlier in relation to the
predicaments of the classical and neo-classical schools, wherein
ethics remained exogenous to economic matters. Because of a similar
ethical exogeneity in Keynes’s economic system, one cannot decipher
the ethical elements of productive ventures into which resources are
to be directed for attaining simultaneous general equilibria in the
four sectors earlier mentioned.
|
Ethics and Economics: Recent Economic Thought
We have shown that both in
the case of microeconomics emanating from the classical and
neo-classical economic thought and macroeconomics from Keynesianism,
the integration of ethics into economic values and market exchange
remained a central focus. Yet such a goal defied the scientific
methodologies of these schools. Ethics and economics were indeed
epistemologically thought to be inseparable in all of economic thought
from the very beginning. The problem of blending the two appeared due
to the absence of what we claimed is a process-based systemic
explanation of the social, economic and scientific universe. A
substantive methodology of process orientation could otherwise have
integrated and unified ethics with the purely economic elements.
The problem that economics has always encountered is therefore one of
rendering a socio-scientific paradigm that can treat ethics in it as
an endogenous value element with the full force of a substantive
scientific analysis (Bohr
1985,Einstein undated). In other words, epistemologically once again,
we are searching for a worldview that would unify the knowledge
premises of all disciplines according to a systemic framework of
interactions, convergence and creative emergence.
In recent times feverish search has been launched for such a paradigm.
We are not to lose sight of Herbert Simon’s classical book,
Models of Man
(1957). There is also the
Austrian economic orientation in innovative development that was
particularly mastered by
Schumpeter
(1934), but which faded with the coming of the new-classicical concept
of market catalysis in
Hayek’s
work (1976). Such systemic learning-by-doing ways of re-thinking
economic processes are once again occupying increasing interest in
recent times (Georgescu-Roegen
1971,
Kirzner
1997).
The birth of evolutionary economics followed the works of
Boulding
(1967, 1968). The main thrust of these studies is in the direction of
explaining dis-equilibrium, chaotic and even equilibrium-converging
models of social reality. Yet recent literature on evolutionary
economics could not disentangle itself from neo-classical economic
methodology (Nelson
&
Winter
1982). Hence a substantive theory of knowledge in economic change is
fading away from evolutionary economics under the neo-classical
influence. Recently, the social contractarian approach of
Buchanan
(1975), Buchanan &
Tollison
(1972) and the historistic economic studies propounded by
North
(1981) have also tied our attention to the search by the economic
academia for a process-oriented explanation of economics, society,
institution, politics and constitution (Choudhury
1998a)
Sen’s Ethics and Economics
Among the very important
contributions given to the field of ethics and economics are by
Sen
(1990). Of particular interest are Sen’s philosophical writings in
re-orientating social welfare and social choice theories in the
direction of explaining economic preferences that can be functionally
determined by ethics. Here Sen ventures in examining how individual
preferences can be formulated by imputing the sense of rights and
duties in them (deontological) and thus explaining the consequences of
such rights and duty bound preferences in market exchange (consequentialism).
Sen’s ideas of social well-being are premised on such deontological
consequentialism ans examined analytically. The social and interactive
aspects of studying such preference formulation by analytical methods
are evident in Sen words (1990, p. 75): "To get an overall assessment
of the ethical standing of an activity it is necessary not only to
look at its instrumental role and its consequences on other things,
i.e. to examine the various intrinsically valuable or disvaluable
consequences that this activity may have. What was called the
‘engineering’ aspect of economics has a parallel within ethics itself.
It may not be as central in many ethical problems as it is in
mainstream economics, but it can be important enough."
What is then the methodological problem with these more recent
attempts in explaining ethico-economic integration in the light of a
systems orientation? An answer to this question is found in noting
that the neo-classical assumptions of bounded economic rationality
remains intrinsic in the postulates of social choice, welfare
economics, institutional economics and public choice theory. Along the
line of academic discourse launched by Sen and several philosophers,
most notably
Rawls
(1971),
Nozick
(1971) and
Dworkin
(1978) in recent times;
Kant
(1964),
Hume
(1992),
Husserl
(1965) and
Hegel
(1956) of an earlier vintage, there remains a lack of substantiating
the premise of a fundamental epistemology explaining unity of
knowledge pertaining to ethico-economics.
The social and economic doctrines referred to here are left instead to
a concept of unity that breeds on the rationality perspectives of
mental plurality, or else there exists no essential premise to
foundationally define the episteme of unity of knowledge. New quests
are today appearing in the intellectual domain of unity of knowledge
in the physical sciences, but to date the inquiries have been limited
to the unification of physical reality alone and that too without
definite success (Barrow
1991,
Hawking
1988). On the other side, the classical works on unity of the sciences
could not establish a fundamentally pervasive methodology for the
sciences (Neurath
et al 1970,
Nagel 1961). In
economic theory we find the dichotomy of economic reasoning,
inference, perception, price level and output between microeconomics
and macroeconomics. Such a methodological dichotomy is also the case
with the ideas of large scale and small scale universes of theoretical
physics.
The idea of plurality as a necessity but posing a deep problem of
measurement and harmonization of methodology can be found in Sen’s
works. Sen finds unacceptable problem with a unified or ‘monist’
scientific approach. He writes in this regard with a view of rejecting
the idea of ‘monist’ unity (Sen
1990, p.62): "Not only is there a unified and complete view of ethical
goodness (weighing the different objects of value vis-à-vis each
other), but even the objects of value must be all of the same type
(singular and homogeneous) in this ‘monist’ conception."
|
Need for Endogenous Ethics in Economics; Systems
Approach
Now
at the end, it is again the properties of neo-classical preferences
despite their invoking of ethical questions that negate the place of
unification of knowledge across agency, goods, systems and their
interrelations. Ethics in such a rarified premise of rationalist plurality
cannot be epistemologically endogenized within a systemic framework that
can be endowed by extensive and strong interactions across all systems.
Though even with such a universal re-configuration of scientific
epistemology, problem specificity across disciplines will remain, but the
methodology will be uniquely unified
Thus for a real breakthrough in the domain of ethics and economics we are
to continue our search for an epistemological premise that can
scientifically establish and then explain ethics as an endogenous reality
of all systems. A particular one of such systems is the economy and
markets, interacting agents and institutions, their needs and social
relations. Having rejected the reasoning of mainstream economics with
respect to an endogenous treatment of ethics we are left searching for
that fundamental unity of knowledge at the epistemological core of a
scientific understanding, explanation and application. We must establish
such a methodology of general systems across all disciplines. This is
indeed a search for a meta-theory of systemic unity with extensive
interdisciplinary explanatory power.
Thus we enter the study of the structure of Islamic economics. Even here,
Islamic Economics is a terminology that we must finally have to abandon
because of its blind following of the methodology of mainstream economic
and ethical doctrines, which can hardly be defended on grounds of the
precept of unity of knowledge found in the Qur’an, Sunnah.
The Structure of Islamic Systems Oriented Reasoning
: Endogenizing Ethics
With the limitations posed by ethically-neutral perspectives of economic
theory premised on the axioms of economic rationality and philosophical
rationalism and on the inherent plurality of knowledge in these, unity of
knowledge across systems can neither be defined nor attained. This
debility has stood in the way of treating ethics endogenously within
socio-scientific comprehension.
In Islamic socio-scientific worldview the fundamental root of knowledge is
the Unity of God. This Precept of Oneness is both of the essence of the
unity of Being as well as the unity of Divine Laws. The Divine Laws are
seen as the spring of absolute and complete knowledge. While the ontology
of Divine Oneness is not manifest, yet the epistemology of the
world-system premised on Divine Oneness is manifested in terms of the
unity of knowledge. Such an externalizing of the Divine Laws reveals the
fundamental unity of Being, of the Divine Laws and of the world-systems
constructed on these. The Qur’an is profuse with verses invoking and
exhorting human beings to search out the signs of divine unity in the
order of things by contemplation and observation.
Islamic reality is thus an expression of the Signs of God in terms of His
Oneness as expressed in the fundamentally unified essence of the universe
and of everything in it. The structure of Islamic economics, taken to mean
the epistemology of Islamic economics, is premised on the unity of
knowledge in its ontological and empirical sense.
But although God is One and complete and absolute in knowledge, He has
bestowed only a little of this knowledge to world-systems including
individuals, societies and scientific universes embedded in world-systems.
Yet within this limited scope of knowledge He has created stages of
advance that are attained by a progressive and incessant comprehension of
the Divine Laws and His Signs. These are comprehended through
God-conscious search. Consequently, the dynamics of knowledge production
in understanding the unified nature of the universe, its systems and
sub-systems are based on incrementalism, God-consciousness and the
consequential development of cognitive powers (observations). Reason then
becomes the result of such attributes that come to the inquirer from his
conscious search for the Signs of God in world-systems.
What is Knowledge?
The concept of knowledge that
we will use throughout this paper should be explained now. Knowledge that
is absolute and complete with God is the Complete Stock of Reality. It
neither waxes nor wanes; it is not observable entirely, but is always
comprehended in increments. The Stock of Knowledge is the source of all
knowing in world-systems. Entities, be they human or non-human, including
systems variables and their relations, learn in an interactive mode to
reach increasing consciousness by deriving flows of learning inputs from
the Stock of Knowledge. Since the Stock is fundamentally unified in the
sense of Divine Oneness as its cardinal attribute, therefore, derived
knowledge flows are of the same essence of unity. Interactions are thus
epistemologically made to converge to the comprehension of reality.
Comprehension, observation and construct in Islamic world-systems are
determined by the emergence of such flows of knowledge premised on
fundamental unity. Such derived forms then generate the world-systems. The
knowledge-induced world-systems thereafter, generate new springs of
knowledge flows.
While the Oneness of God gives the Complete Stock of Knowledge, ‘flows of
knowledge’ (or ‘knowledge flows’) on the other hand, constitute learning
in the universe on grounds of the epistemology of fundamental unity. This
learning experience is to acquire God-consciousness, to observe the Signs
of God and to construct world-systems by means of that consciousness.
Interactions leading to integration and further emerging to new rounds of
interrelationships between fundamental epistemology of unity and the
unified world-systems premised on this consciousness, determine the
experience of knowledge flows.
Incrementalism in knowledge flows as so attained marks the progressive
advance of individuals and societies and with these of world-systems into
greater springs of knowing. It also means the reality of differentiating
truth from falsehood in this same progressive mode. The creative and
evolutionary powers so acquired by the agents and world-systems are
explained in the various designs, methods and mechanisms of man. What
emerges from such an intellectual inquiry is the search by increments of
knowledge flows premised on Divine Unity (Divine Laws) for the essence of
the universe that is fundamentally unified in its revealed form across
diversity.
These attributes of unification epistemology form the three core parts of
the methodology of Islamic socio-scientific systemic analysis as
schematized here:
Complete Stock=Full and Absolute Knowledge (Divine Laws)
® S Acquired Knowledge [1]
® I World-System [2]
® I Creative Evolution to more knowledge [3]
® I repetitive cyclical continuity in this order.
Here, Complete Stock denotes Divine Knowledge as embodied in the Qur’an.
‘S’ denotes Sunnah (enlightened guidance of Prophet Muhammad) and the role
it plays in the order of comprehension, acquired knowledge and application
of the Divine Laws in world-systems. The combination of Qur’an and Sunnah
establishes the Fundamental Epistemology of Unity for human reason and
cognition. From these roots arises the core of Islamic Laws (Shari’ah).
The World-System is any selected domain with diversity in accordance with
the issues and problems under study and in which unity of knowledge is
reflected. Thus there exists the axiom or the ‘principle of universal
complementarity’ that unifies the diverse number of events in
world-systems according to their acceptability of similars. These are the
separate categories of truth and falsehood as Qur’anically understood.
They are seen to be systemically unified in themselves but as being
mutually exclusive to each other. Falsehood is termed here as
‘de-knowledge’ (Choudhury
1995a). Its
attribute in the unification plane is one of maintaining the essentially
rationalist, random and pluralistic character of individualism that it
endows. Note is to be made of the quite distinctive use of the term
‘world-system’ in the sense of worldview developed in this paper from that
for the power centric concept of capitalist world-system given by
Wallerstein
(1974).
‘I’ denotes the process of discovering rules of life and thought from the
fundamental sources of Qur’an and Sunnah. While the epistemological core
of Shari’ah lies in the Qur’an and Sunnah, the worldly details of Shari’ah
are simulated by the discursive process of ‘I’. Some of these discourses
belong to the area of formulation of appropriate rules, methods,
instruments, policies and institutions. The process of interactions is
explained in the Qur’an to exist in both the animate and inanimate realms.
Hence there are interactions among agents, institutions, entities,
variables, systems and their interrelations.
Next, these interactions among diversities of world-systems lead to
integration (also referred to as consensus and convergence). Thus there is
convergence is a limiting process attained through interactions
(discourse) among a plethora of discursive knowledge flows on the issues
under investigation.
After interactions lead to integration, a creative order of world-systems
is re-generated by further emerging springs of knowledge flows from the
acquired experience of previously knowledge-induced world-systems.
Creative evolution is premised on the same process as explained so far.
Such a complete process that takes the unity of knowledge as the
epistemological premise for understanding world-systems through
interactions leading to integration and followed by creative evolution in
continuity, is the Qur’anic dialectical process of shura. We will call
this knowledge inducing process to and from creative world-systems as the
shuratic process. It is to be noted here that the shuratic process is
taken in the vastly universal meaning of interactions as presented by the
Qur’an and not simply that which is restricted to the political domain.
Endogeneity of Ethics in Islamic Socio-Scientific Order
Endogeneity of ethics in
Islamic socio-scientific world-systems means the realization of the
shuratic process in determining possibilities of life and thought
according to Shari’ah. These possibilities then determine world-systems.
To these world-systems belong markets and the economy. Now such human
realms do not and cannot exist in isolation of the greater complex of
human systems. Such a systemic interrelationship is necessary in order to
maintain the strong and pervasive interactions, integration and creative
evolution across extensions realized with the progress of knowledge flows
rising from lower to higher levels of certainty.
According to Ibn al-Arabi and the atomism philosophy of the Asharites (Qadri
1988) the universe was seen to be pervasively of the essence of the
Oneness of God in the order of things. Ibn al-Arabi wrote on the process
of knowledge formation (Chittick
1989):
Two ways lead to the knowledge of God. There is no third way….
The first way is the way of unveiling. It is an incontrovertible knowledge
which is actualized through unveiling and which man finds in himself. He
receives no obfuscations along with it and is not able to repel it. He
knows no proof for it by which it is supported except what he finds in
himself….
The second way is the way is the way of reflection and reasoning (istidlal)
through rational demonstration (burhan ‘aqli). This way is lower than the
first way, since he who bases his consideration upon proof can be visited
by obfuscations which detract from his proof, and only with difficulty can
he remove them."
Ibn al-Arabi continues on to write as translated by Chittick:
Any knowledge outside of tawhid (Oneness of God) leads away from God, not
toward Him. But knowledge within the context of tawhid leads its possessor
to grasp the interconnectedness of all things through a vast web whose
Center is the Divine. All existences come from God and go back to Him"
[edited].
According to Imam Ghazzali in his Ihya Ulum Id-Din (Vol..2) (Epistemology
of Divine Knowledge), Shari’ah is formulated by the reformation of the
self and soul away from wants (Karim
undated). In fact it is reported that
Ghazzali
never believed in the market function determining the law of demand
relating prices and quantities as in the classical economic school.
Instead, he considered all price fluctuations to be an act of God and not
of any law of demand. The deep import here is that endogenous ethical
elements in market exchange can alter the assumed axiomatic predictive
relation between price and quantity in the demand function (Islahi
1995).
According to Imam Fakhruddin Razi the basis of life is obedience to God
which he takes as the root and essence of needs fulfillment (Noor
1995). Razi can be seen as the much earlier forerunner of the recent days
social psychology theory of self-actualization given by Maslow. For a
schematic design of this process see Lutz (1988). However, the structure
of the needs fulfillment theory of obedience to God (Ubudiyya) given by
Razi is inverse of Maslow’s and exists in continuum not in heierachies as
in Malslow’s (Choudhury
1995b).
According to Imam Shatibi in his Muwafaqat fil-Usul al-Shari’ah (Treatise
on the Epistemology of Shari’ah), the rights of individuals are formed by
the principle of social well-being through discourse and opinion (Choudhury
1993). These are the social interactions leading to integration in or
paper. Muwafaqat gave the early version of the concept of social
well-being in Shatibi’s theory of Al-Maslaha wal-Istihsan, a study of
social preference making through discourse on issues of public purpose.
Such ideas have come into economics only recently.
According to Ibn Taimiyyah in his Al-Hisbah Fil Islam (Social Guidance of
Markets), the needs of social justice prevails over unbridled market
competition. Hence a socially acceptable ethical guidance of markets was
seen to be necessary (Holland 1983). This was seen to be necessary despite
that Ibn Taimiyyah’s did not dispel the importance of market process that
is so clearly promoted by Shari’ah.
According to Shah Waliullah in his Hujjatullah Baligah (Introduction to
the Study of Social Change), historical change is a complex of
interrelationships among emerging systems and stages of life starting from
primitive societies to advanced ones. These ideas of Waliullah’s theory of
social change are discussed by
Ghazali
(1990).
In all of these classical contributions to social and economic thinking
among leading Islamic scholars we note the epistemology of Oneness of God
and Shari’ah as the conveyor of that Oneness into life and action has
played central role in determining all kinds of rules and conduct for
individual and social life. We also find in these the presence of
knowledge-induced interactive and integrative approach to social meaning.
Consequently, the concept and formulation of social well-being, contrary
to the theoretical impasse caused by the plurality doctrine of
philosophical rationalism, individual rational choices and social choice
in Sen’s writing, is seen in the Islamic framework to be the result of a
substantive process. This shuratic process emerges from, subsequently
realizes, and then creatively evolves along the unification process of
knowledge flows. In this very process individuals and society are
conformably transformed across and within themselves. Systems thus unify
across agents, variables and their interrelations.
Markets According to the Principle of Ethical
Endogeneity in Islamic Economics
We will now
characterize the nature of markets in the Islamic endogenous ethico-economic
order. Contrary to Smith’s invisible hands principle and the assumed
post-hoc optimality of resource allocation where learning and
knowledge cease at the points of optimum and equilibrium either in the
midst of full or bounded information (rationality), markets in the
Islamic order are ethically guided although not intervened unduly by
institutions.
The interactive, integrative and evolutionary nature (henceforth IIE)
of the shuratic process implies that market contracts are continuously
made according to simulating rules, choices and resource allocations
premised on Shari’ah guided economic and financial instruments. Such
processes of discourse and contracts generate continuous flows of
knowledge. The interacting legal, ethical, material and institutional
elements mark the nature of inter-systemic interactions. On the other
hand, the complementarity among prices and quantities for the Shari’ah
prescribed orders continuously enhanced by knowledge flows, defines a
resource allocation and pricing behaviour that is quite contrary to
the methods prescribed by marginal utility on the demand side and by
marginal productivity on the supply side. Technological change in the
demand, supply, production and social well-being functions is seen as
transformation through which emerging processes of requisite knowledge
flows are realized and transmitted for implementation in order to
attain complementarity across diversity.
The Social Well-Being Function and the Social Well-Being Index
The social
well-being function is now seen as the benefit derived from the
consumption choices of bundles of goods and services determined by a
continuing shuratic process enabling complementary choices to occur (Choudhury
1996). The concept of utility function is replaced by individual
choices of goods and services that are complementary in themselves in
providing benefits. Such benefits are themselves the result of another
level of complementarity. This is the complementarity between
knowledge and material objectivity. Instead of consumer utilities,
social well-being indexes understood in the sense of complementarity
among goods and services for consumption purposes, functionally
characterize the social well-being function (Choudhury 1992).
The Production Menu
The production
menu is the result of complementarity between labour and capital (also
other factors of production) in the knowledge-augmented form. This is
an issue of technological change, the choice of the goods to produce
and to consume, and the institutional participation required to
determine such choices by discourse. Thus by the idea of
complementarity among factors and goods in the production menu we mean
such a complementarity being realized by interactions, integration and
creative evolution in the shuratic processes pertaining to a complex
of participation among social agents, individuals, variables and their
interrelations.
Resources and Prices of Goods and Services
Resources are
continuously augmented by knowledge flows. Through the emerging
diversities of economic possibilities and complementarity among them,
risk and product diversification occurs. Thereby, cost and risk
decline. Such a resource generation can be the result of many factors:
avoidance of waste, new discoveries through active productive
investments, participatory enterprises that develop human resources,
choices of dynamic forms of needs fulfillment development regimes,
institutional organization based on cooperation and extensive joint
ventures, and formal as well as informal ways of guiding the economic
agents towards proper modes of production and consumption menus (Choudhury
1998b).
Prices in such a resource allocation system are those resulting from
complementarity among goods and services. That is, they are determined
by market exchange with complementarity embedded in it. This property
of Islamic resource allocation is similar to price determination in
classical economic theory, but the goods are ethically induced by
knowledge input from continuously guiding social institutions. Such
prices can only occur as a result of extensive systemic linkages,
whereby participation in the broad sense of complementarity exists.
Also they are the result of a needs-oriented economy where
complementarity is necessary to sustain diversity. Development regimes
are thus of the dynamic (i.e. evolutionary) needs-oriented type. In
this sense therefore, the Islamic market is not different from a
classical economic market in terms of the needs-oriented goods and
services exchanged. However, ethical endogeneity in exchange alters
the nature of exchange relations.
Profits
Because of this
nature of the Islamic economy, profits are generated on the basis of
near normal profits, since market contracts will determine the margin
of error in the pricing of goods for profits that can be subsequently
shared among partners. Such errors in market contracts can result from
non-optimal learning games that participants play between themselves.
Between consumers and suppliers, prices in exchange are determined by
the ethical response to appropriate goods from the side of the
knowledge-induced demand and preference functions of the consumer. To
this the supply function and the production function respond. Besides,
production menus are of the participatory type with discourses and
decision making occurring between labour and owners. Such a
participatory environment also determines the nature of goods and the
menus of production with social awareness in them.
Profits are near normal profits also because of the regime of dynamic
basic needs baskets of goods and services that are demanded and
supplied in the Islamic economy. Such dynamic needs fulfillment
baskets preserve price stability and make the revenues depend
principally on the production side. From the side of an appropriate
choice of technology, such a regime of development likewise causes
profits to be generated on the basis of output. Thus output plays a
primary role in the participatory nature of sharing in the resources
and returns of production. Prices remain stable at each evolutionary
juncture of dynamic basic needs regimes of development. The picture is
similar to the classical treatment of needs in market exchange. Yet
the resource allocation occurs through complementarity between goods,
services and agents of demand and supply. This becomes a function of
knowledge flows that enable such complementary interactions to occur
and then lead to integration and dynamic emergence of choices of the
basic needs regimes of development..
Factor Pricing
On the side of
pricing of factors of production, the derived demand for factors are
functions of factor prices and prices of goods and service. Since
productive factors remain complementary due to the factor-augmenting
technological change, therefore, their prices also move in the same
direction. In all of these cases, knowledge flows as interactions
leading to integration and creative evolution of new knowledge as a
dynamic process, play the fundamental role.
The supply of factors of production is not based on factor marginal
productivities. Rather, it is determined by the effect transmitted by
the demand side. Hence here too, much of the equilibrium aspects of
classical factor markets exist, but now with endogenous ethical
effects in existence, as caused by the continuous production of
knowledge.
Economic Distribution
Between the
demand and supply sides of the factor and product markets we now have
the resolution of the economic distribution problem. The true worth of
the things exchanged, be these goods or services of factors, is based
on their value as determined by use in exchange and by intrinsic value
embedded in them. Intrinsic value is discovered through ethically
induced market exchange. Although such a value is not measurable yet
it influences the net price in exchange. The concept of value in
exchange is now that of net value of effort and exchange after
intrinsic value, as naturally embedded in the exchangeables, is
discounted from the price as a return either to the seller or the
productive factor. Intrinsic value is not observed but it is revealed
through morally conscious (preference formation) exchange in
ethicizing markets toward determining supply prices
Idea of Priorities and Specialization
In the milieu of
complementarity among factors and the simultaneous movement of their
prices determining similar consequences on prices in the market for
goods and services, the additional question is that of economic
priority and specialization. We have already explained that ‘the
principle of universal complementarity across diversity’ in the space
of goods, factors, resources and prices, completely negates the
neo-classical postulate of marginal substitution.
Similar concepts of marginalism that have inhibited scientific
analyses of steady-state change are also re-conceptualized in terms of
knowledge-induced simulative methods (Choudhury 1998c). Thus our
examination of the topic of priority and specialization must be based
on the principle of universal complementarity across diversity in all
systems. The principle remains a view polar to the postulate of
marginalism( Daly 1992).
If one were to further represent such a knowledge-induced resource
allocation across economic possibilities, the trajectory of the
allocation will be a perturbed path. Perturbations here are the result
of continuous induction of variables and events by knowledge flows.
That means both the concept and the methods of optimality and
optimization are dispensed with in the light of the attribute of
knowledge formation. As we explained earlier, such knowledge flows
evolve incrementally through the dynamics of the shuratic process. In
spite of the perturbed nature of simulative trajectories, integrity of
the knowledge-induced pattern of evolution is maintained as long as
knowledge flows are continuously evolved and integrated through
interactions. Thus there exist evolutionary equilibria in the Islamic
resource allocation regimes in the sense of sustaining the pattern of
shuratic epiphenomenon (Grandmont 1989).
Priority of choice in knowledge-induced resource allocation would
nonetheless imply that certain possibilities are incrementally used,
preferred and demanded more than other ones. Yet such a choice
reflects simply a measurement of the relative degree of variations in
the alternatives over space and time. But, in spite of such
variations, the movements of alternatives keep in tact the
monotonically positive directions of all prices. The idea of
prioritizing choices therefore, does not mean marginal substitution of
one for another. Rather, the first order change always remains
positive, although the second order change may be relatively negative
and varying according to the existing moments of knowledge induction
as the simulation of the shuratic process proceeds.
Other arguments arising from the side of the principle of universal
complementarity that annuls the neo-classical postulate of marginalism,
are that any reversal to a marginalist picture in resource allocation
in Islamic markets is a case of temporary or permanent slowdown in
knowledge production. In the case of a temporary slowdown in knowledge
production we have an instantaneously very short-run event. Such an
event has no significance in economic movements and change. On the
other hand, only in the case of the long-run permanent demise of
knowledge flows can a full return to neoclassical resource allocation
be possible. Such a neo-classical state of resource allocation would
be once again described by optimal and non-sharing agents. These are
also the characteristics of methodological individualism, earlier
referred to in terms of independence and marginalism among competing
agents. In all such cases the meaning of interactions breeding
knowledge flows, process and reality, is lost.
Specialization is seen in the shuratic process order as the
‘intensity’ of certain choices of technologies and means of production
to develop linkages across sectors, goods, resources, factors of
production and other possibilities. Such linkages being direct
functions of knowledge flows caused by the existence of
complementarity across diversity, would mean the development of
possibilities in the economic space as caused by interactions.
Consequently, while specialization would continue to mean an efficient
method of attaining output, such a method would not remain opaque but
rather will be transparent to all cooperating agents. This idea of a
specialization process comes nearer to the innovative learning process
of the Austrian economic school that allows for systemic interactions
to remain embryonic in the innovative specializing paths of
entrepreneurship.
|
The Central Role of the Principle of Universal
Complementarity across Diversity
In
the end we note that the knowledge-induced structure of Islamic market
economy is premised on complementarity within diversity. These are signs
of integration (complementarity), which is a cardinal sign of unity of
knowledge arising from interactions (diversity). They are then evolved to
reproduce knowledge that empowers the further understanding of unity, and
thereby, of organizing the emerging world-systems. The study of Islamic
markets and economy cannot therefore, be an isolated study of pure and
simply economic matters alone. Rather as the meaning of specialization in
this system was explained, economic structure as any other disciplinary
structure in the light of Qur’an, Sunnah and Ijtihad (deriving knowledge
from the primal epistemological sources), is inter- and intra-systemically
unified through the shuratic process. This is the process that reveals
knowledge and organizes it in world-systems through the methodology of
understanding, observing and realizing interactions within integrating
orders leading to continuously creative evolution of the same.
The Instruments of Islamic Economy
In light of the
IIE process-centered understanding of socio-scientific reality, all
Islamic economic and financial instruments are to be taken up in such
a systemically unified knowledge-induced general equilibrium
framework. The instruments so developed can then be explained in terms
of causal interrelationships. The epistemology of Divine Unity and its
reflection in these instruments can then be made to explain the
endogenous nature of ethics (i.e. knowledge flows) within a systemic
world view of unity of knowledge.
The five major Islamic economic and financial instruments are, (1)
abolition of interest, (2) profit-sharing under economic cooperation
between labour and capital, (3) joint ventures, principally though not
wholly through equity participation; (4) the institution of charity;
(5) avoidance of wasteful use of resources. Many more instruments can
be evolved from a combination of these five.
Abolition of Interest
In the general
systems-oriented understanding of Islamic ethico-economics, the
ethical and economic meaning of abolition of interest are fused
together. Let us then understand why abolition of interest becomes
mandatory in such a framework of analysis.
The presence of interest in financial and economic activities implies
dissociation between two major sectors of the economy. These are the
monetary sector and the productive sector. Money is treated as a
commodity of the monetary sector. Its price is made to capitalize risk
that indeed can be avoided in alternative ways. Risk is assumed to
exist ex-ante because the holder of money can subjectively assign risk
and then impute it in his price for money, which is the rate of
interest. Hence assuming ex-ante risk to exist generates earnings to
the money lender. Alternatively however, risk could have been avoided
or reduced by resource mobilization, instead of holding it in the bank
or in speculative outlets. Money is not saved but mobilized in the
real economic sectors to earn real economic returns. The real sector
then pays off the returns on loanable funds.
In the macroeconomy as well, the policy to stabilize inflation, to
slow down the excess demand for investment resources, and attract
world savings into the national economy, reflect the government’s
approach to make the monetary sector act independently of the real
sector. In these cases the rate of interest is used as a basic
monetary instrument. Consequently, the potentiality for reducing
macroeconomic instability and dis-equilibrium otherwise by generating
real sectoral linkage with money capital flows, is ignored. The end
result is that the monetary sector gains over the real sector through
the profits earned on loanable funds. The two sectors are thus once
again de-linked through such a competition.
Knowing that the rich gain from the money markets in terms of earnings
of interest and the poor gains by real sectoral activity, the above
independence between the two sectors can be seen to adversely affect
the poor. The ethical acquisition of wealth and the social order are
thereby made increasingly unjust. Indeed, in recent times the feverish
run for interest-bearing speculative funds in the global financial
markets have left the national economies in disorder and their poor
adversely affected on all fronts.
In terms of the intertemporal accumulative nature of savings seen as
withdrawal of spending from potential productive ventures, this causes
those who hold money to take advantage by earning interest on such
savings. Savings thus become an incentive that is causally related
with interest rates. The separation of savings as an economic activity
from the activity of spending causes competition between the money
market and the product market. Savings draw resources into the
monetary sector. Resources thereby, leave the real sector when
interest rate prevails as an incentive to savings against spending.
Savings thus once again cause the economy to be de-linked between
these competing sectors and activities. Indeed the neutrality of
monetary policy on full-employment income is the result of an economy
in which the real sector has become unyielding. This leaves the
monetary sector to be unyielding on productivity.
The outlook of the Islamic economy is to make spending as the basis of
resource mobilization. Thus when households put monies in Islamic
banks, such funds are to be mobilized by the banks in order to earn
returns from permissible productive investments. The return on such
resources is the return on the real sectoral venture. There is no
return of money on money. Money is simply an ex-post medium for
servicing the real sectoral demand for permissible and productive
activities. Risk is shared between agents and sectors in terms of the
magnitude of the real sectoral rates of return. The concept of saving
as withdrawal from spending is replaced by the idea of resource
mobilization into permissible and productive investments through
Islamic banks. Banks must rapidly turn money capital into real capital
through entrepreneurial activities (Choudhury 1997)..
Contrary to the resource mobilization mechanism, interest bearing
financing window determines a subjectively advance estimate for
uncapitalized risk to the savers or the borrower in the hope that they
can secure a guaranteed return on savings. This price, which is the
rate of interest, is a marginal substitution rate on real yield.
Intertemporal discounting then ensues in the subjective capitalization
method for evaluating risky ventures in an interest-based financial
system. Discount rates used are neither objective nor risk-free. The
very existence of uncapitalized risk and its pricing by the rate of
interest over time implies a permanent constriction of the flow of
resources into the real sector. This kills entrepreneurial spirit. An
economy cannot be sustained along a development path in such uncertain
and socially costly conditions.
Profit-sharing Under Economic Cooperation
In order to
replace interest transactions, the Islamic economy provides incentives
to mobilize resources into permissible and productive joint ventures.
Through such participation and extension of cooperative agents and
projects across the economy, an effective diversification of
production, investments and risk is attainable. Thus risk pricing by
means of the rate of interest is replaced by expected rates of
returns. The real sectoral returns are shared ex-post by the
participants in cooperative ventures. The marginalizing competition
between the monetary sector and the real sector, between owners of
capital and labour, and thus between the rich and poor caused by the
prevalence of interest, are all replaced by participatory ventures. In
this way, resource mobilization through profit-sharing is causally
related with complementarity among economic activities and agents.
In the production sector, complementarity between factors of
production (capital and labour) is brought about by the choice of
equally capital-labour augmenting technological change and by
extensive participatory ventures economy-wide. Now both entitlement
and empowerment, which are consequences of participatory
decision-making and cooperative sharing of risk and returns, are
realized. In the macroeconomy, the monetary sector where the financial
capitalists prevail, and the productive sector where labour prevails,
are interconnected by means of complementarity between these sectors
and agents.
In Islamic profit-sharing under economic cooperation, because of the
exclusive liability of capital in joint ventures, capital owners
assume all financial costs in the case of losses and business
dissolution. On the other hand, labour can opt to delay taking
dividends and/or defer portions of wage payments in such participatory
enterprises. There are however, innovative methods that can be
established to circumvent the problem of risk and costs in
enterprises. One such option is a development fund generated with
accruals from wages and profits for use during times of exigency. Such
pooled funds can also be treated as a wage and corporate insurance.
The range of enterprise linkages and activities is thus broadened and
diversified. The result is risk and product diversification.
The concept of sharing time as an investment resource by labour for a
deferred return can be considered as another innovative means of
capitalizing shareholding between capital and labour in an enterprise
and among many enterprises for that matter. All of these possibilities
affirm the principle of complementarity among factors, resources,
goods, ventures and sectors through a production relationship that is
contrary to the de-linking nature of interest-based financing of
enterprise (Vanek 1977).
Variable contracts in profit-sharing between capital and labour is yet
another mode that can increasing the entitlement of labour and
generate more resource flows in the economy through heightened
participation and wealth mobilization. In a purely participatory
Islamic economy such kinds of variable financial contracts would also
be linked with choices on options and links by way of indexes of
financial holding in the emerging resources and investment funds.
Joint Ventures and Equity Participation
Owners of capital
can cooperate with each other in extending their investment resources
and also in diversifying risk and ventures by outlays over an
expanding economic space. Risk and product diversification so caused
by extension of pooled resources also removes the relevance of
interest pricing of risk, in which case money and product markets
remain detached and compete for independent gains. Interest rates are
thus effectively replaced by actual ex-post sharing of returns on
ventures with realized and fully evaluated risk.
Although Islamic economists have treated profit-sharing and equity
participation in separate ways, there is neither reason for nor
efficacy in doing so. Since capital and labour are complementary in
the Islamic economy and equity participation is another cooperative
mechanism among capitalists, therefore, increasing numbers of
enterprise and labour are realized and interconnected by a mix between
profit-sharing and equity-participation, both taken up as
participatory entrepreneurial activities.
Consequently, in the case of equity-participation a contractual
undertaking between owners of capital is also a contract between
capital and labour and thus between and among all. This means a
systemic extension of the resource mobilization process across the
Islamic economy. Such an extensive participation must be upheld if
interest is to be eliminated. Hence the principle of complementarity
relates money capital to productive ventures. In the same way, joint
ventures and equity-participation must serve the wider empowering and
entitlement generating effects of labour and capital within an
entrepreneurial framework with increasing decision-making
possibilities.
In a systemic view of the Islamic economy there is no need to
particularly differentiate profit-sharing from equity-financing,
except to identify the sources of funds and the contractual claims on
dividends by the participants. But in the general systems framework
the causal interrelationships among resource flows from one to another
do not make a difference in terms of specificity of the sources of
funds. Registering the specificity of sources of such funds is not of
any economic significance; it is simply a matter for legal and
accounting viablity of contracts.
In such a general systems framework it is interesting to examine the
role that such resource flows can play in establishing a dynamic
equilibrium system with endogenous ethics in it. Ethics is represented
in Islamic systemic world-systems by their intrinsic presence in all
entities as knowledge flows derived epistemologically. Thus when
universal complementarity prevails across diversity in the Islamic
economy, unity in this sense is to be taken as a sign of unification
of knowledge of the various agencies, sectors, variables and their
relations. Such a complementary process is realized through
participation. This is realized through the above two financial
instruments. It is also reflected in terms of engineering methods that
enable such evolutionary systems of interactions and integration to be
analytically studied (Shakun 1988).
The Institution of Charity
Charity in Islam
has a wide meaning. Zakah as charity is a mandatory take on wealth for
specific purposes of meeting a wide range of social responsibilities
as explained in the Qur’an (Chapter 2, verse 177). One of these social
mandates is poverty alleviation. Here zakah guarantees basic needs to
the needy and establishes social as well as distributive justice. The
use of zakah can be seen as an example of the deontological (rights
and duties) aspect of ethical market transformation. ‘Deontological
consequentialism’ of markets is a social problem that we showed has
occupied Sen’s interest in his theory of social well-being and
agency.
Sadaqah is another form of charity. It is exclusively voluntary and
meant to be spent on the destitute. There is however, no reason why
sadaqah cannot be organized on the same format as zakah. This
inference follows from a verse of the Qur’an that identifies the two
with similar modes of expenditure. See Qur’an, Chapter 2, verses 177
and 215. Verse 177 is specific on zakah, whereas verse 215 mentions
charity broadly, and yet the organization of expenditure is the same.
Consequently, the implication of overall organization of zakah can be
generalized for all forms of charity, including voluntary sadaqah.
The meaning of charity in Islam goes beyond zakah and sadaqah.
Endowing public property for the general benefit of the needy
community (waqf), building an environmental enclave (hima) for
ecological balance, and in general goods and exchanges in society
individually and collectively, are forms of charity. Thus charity
becomes a widely accepted resource flow in the grants economy with the
elements of both a monetary as well as a social asset and returns
associated with it. In this sense, charity induces linkages between
groups and socioeconomic possibilities. The goal is to mobilize
charity for attaining social justice, equality and distributive
justice, and productive transformation of the recipients of charity
and activities in and by the endowed assets.
Charity in Islam is not meant to generate free-ridership. That is, it
is not considered as an outlay without a useful return that favourable
influences socioeconomic transformation. Consequently, charity is to
be understood as a medium for a socially productive mobilization of
excess resources from the wealthy to the needy for enabling both of
these groups to interact, integrate and prosper in the social economy.
The wealthy promotes such integration by participating in the social
needs through spending his excess resources. The needy participates by
utilizing resources in productive activities towards transforming his
state of poverty. This necessitates complementarity among the whole
gamut of inter-sectoral linkages, economy-wide participation, as we
explained earlier. The mutual interest between the rich and poor in
this act of sharing in the charitable enterprise is the prospect of
attaining social stability and a grants economy that delivers social
goods as returns to all.
In such a milieu of productive transformation comes about the
importance of resource flows through the participatory economic
instruments of profit-sharing and equity-participation. The increasing
presence of such instruments in the face of the inverse relationship
between such participatory economic instruments and interest rate,
phases out the interest rate regime. A general systems treatment of
charity as resource augmentation enhances the productive capacity of
the poor along with establishing enterprises for them. Such an
approach can manage to integrate the poor in the hub of mainstream
economic activities, in trade and development, and in entitlement and
empowerment through participatory decision-making, as human resource
advances.
There are many innovative ways in which charitable resources including
zakah and sadaqah can be mobilized for the above kind of productive
and ameliorative transformation. One example is the setting up of a
development fund that will encourage informal labour force activity
including human resource development in the case when below
subsistence wages cause discouragement effects and low calorific
intake by the poor (Choudhury & Hasan 1998). In such a case, wage
exploitation of low-wage earners by employers can be avoided while
productive activity continues on to be enhanced. Such a development
fund can be set up by giving an international perspective to Islamic
charity as a source of resource flows from the wealthy to the needy
groups in the Islamic world. The total mobilization of emerging
productivity of the poor along with the rich through participatory
ventures where zakah funds can be mobilized enhances the total wealth
formation through productive mobilization of resources. This in turn
increases the total national output, resources and wealth.
Indeed, zakah is a claim on wealth, not simply on cash balances and
discretionary income. In the Islamic economy, wealth is formed through
capital mobilization by means of a productive regeneration of returns
in appropriate channels. Such a conception of production of wealth
when combined with the equitable distribution of wealth, which depends
upon charity, most importantly zakah, signifies a linkage between
zakah and the ethical production and distribution of wealth. Zakah
cannot therefore, cause a disincentive effect on the productive
transformation of resources into wealth.
Such a way of generating and distributing wealth is unlike the case of
capital accumulation by means of savings using the instrument of
interest rate. In this case, the presence of interest rate harms
productive activity by limiting the supply of loanable funds and
inflating the cost of investment. The rate of return is then
negatively affected by interest rate. Productive assets and monetary
assets remain competing and negatively affected in the presence of
interest rates as the price of money capital.
Avoidance of Wasteful Use of Resources
The attainment of
all of the above-mentioned Shari’ah instruments is based on the
avoidance of wasteful use of resources that cause leakages in the
socioeconomic system and hence scarcity. Scarcity then returns back to
neo-classical resource allocation and this re-introduces marginalism
and its associated postulate of methodological individualism as we
found in the case of the classical and neo-classical schools. Only
with waste reduced in the economy can diversity be realized and
maintained. Thereby, cost and risk diversification can be attained.
The result is the possibility of attaining complementarity among
possibilities of the real economy in terms of its goods, services,
agents and variables and their various relations.
The avoidance of waste is extended from the demand side to the supply
side (production side). On the demand side the promotion of dynamic
basic needs of life will necessitate a human ecological balance to be
maintained. This will preserve price stability of the Islamic economy
and provide plenty for the sustenance of life. Such preconditions
result in the nature of near normal profit levels. On the production
side the response to the interactive process of knowledge sharing
between consumers and producers will result in the appropriate kinds
of dynamic basic needs to be produced. Consequently, the choice of
production menu based on complementarity between buyers and sellers
and between goods produced is an organizational concept of
biodiversity of production. It is an important part of sustainability
emanating from the production side. Thus in the general systems
perspective of the Islamic economy interactions between the two sides
through interchange of knowledge flows preserve the ecological
balance. Sustainability in such a concept is causally related to the
avoidance of waste.
|
Systemic Linkages among Islamic Financial and
Economic Instruments
We
have pointed out in our discussions on the financial and economic
instruments that there are clear and direct interrelationships among them
in the light of the unique goal of attaining social justice, creating
productive realization of wealth and its equitable distribution in the
Islamic economy. Here is where ethical values converge with economic
instruments according to Shari’ah. The instruments are found to be
causally interrelated by an extensive inter-flow of resources from one
source to another. This enhances the general systems perspective of the
Islamic economy. Thus, ethical endogeneity is systemically realized by
cause and effect through the principle of universal complementarity across
diversities. Such a process is in turn reinforced by risk and product
diversification and inter-sectoral linkages.
Interest rate, which is found to de-link inter-sectoral activities for the
common good is replaced by the rate of return in complementary productive
sectors. The value of money responds to this productive return. The
economic and financial instruments of the Islamic economy thus realize the
principle of universal complementarity, so centrally needed to unify the
economy in its systemic and ethically endogenous sense of knowledge
induction across agencies, systems, variables and their relations.
Conclusion
We
have shown in this paper that the greatest revolution in economic theory
to come will be found in discovering the epistemological methodology of
integrating ethics with economic activities in an endogenous way.
Mainstream economics despite giving a high place to ethics in economic
reasoning could not discover this methodology. The reason for this
debility, as discerned in this paper, is the absence of the premise of
unity of knowledge in its ontological and epistemological sense in
economic theory and other socio-scientific systems. Rationalism as against
the wholeness of an accepted text of laws and conduct of life, causes the
human process to drift into an infinite regress of randomness.
Ethical endogeneity in economics is shown to require its systemic
treatment in a vastly interactive, integrative and evolutionary
knowledge-induced process. We derived this as the shuratic process. In
this, rules and reasoning are developed by a regimented design of social
contract under Shari’ah and not by rationalism. Knowledge is then used as
the invincible and permanent vehicle to carry ethical values to
preferences and from preferences to social transformation. The emerging
general systems of unifying forms premised on the Divine Laws impart the
essence of unity of knowledge in its conceptual and revealed form. This
led to our derivation of the principle of universal complementarity in the
midst of diversity. Such is a derivation from the Qur’anic delineation of
the essential pairedness of the universe and all its entities. The Qur’an
presents the world view of interactive world-systems in terms of its
general systems ecological model of interconnectedness, justice (balance),
purpose, certainty and felicity.
Unity of knowledge and hence unity within ‘de-knowledge’ exists both in
the plane of truth and falsehood, respectively. The difference between
these categories however, is that truth integrates within its own
world-systems by means of unity realized through interactions. This is the
idea of integration in this paper. From interactions leading to
integration emerge creative evolution. On the other hand, falsehood
unifies in its own category by maintaining a pattern of increasing
plurality and alienation within itself. In the case of unity of knowledge
for the truth category, the world is increasingly transformed from a
randomly uncertain one into a certain one. This is the essential function
of creative evolution, which too is the Qur’anic tenet of creative
patterns, search and discovery, all associated with knowledge flows and
their manifestation of the divine signs embodying world-systems.
Finally, on emphasizing the essentially systemic and unified view of
knowledge emanating from Divine Unity and being externalized through the
Divine Laws, we have noted the vastly interactive, integrative and
evolutionary nature of the abiding methodology. Such a methodology, and
thereby, the treatment of general ethico-economic systems in the
endogenous sense, have not been studied in contemporary Islamic economics.
In its absence, the structure of Islamic economics has remained by and
large a mainstream discipline.
We have seen that the mainstream economic methodology does not warrant an
endogenous treatment of ethics in economics. By the same token, the
mainstream economic methodology so far used by Islamic economists has not
enabled a systemic treatment of knowledge induced world-systems, within
which economic problems can be charted. The latter emerging field has led
to a departure as a sign of maturity within the discipline of Islamic
economics. It is today being termed as the field of Islamic Political
Economy.
|
|