| |
INTRODUCING ISLAMIC POLITICAL ECONOMY
Dr.
Masudul Alam Choudhury
MODERN DEVELOPMENTS IN ISLAMIC ECONOMICS
In
recent times, Islamic economics has experienced vigorous pursuit among
Islamic and non-Islamic thinkers alike. The need for IE arose as more and
more Islamic nations got independence from colonial power after World War
II. They faced the challenge of development and self-reliance. Capital
surplus oil exporters came to acquire large sums of wealth, which managed
to establish institutions that were claimed to be run on Islamic
principles of finance, economics and social consciousness. In general, the
claim is made that Islamic Law (Shari'ah) becomes the centerpiece of the
directions of Islamic Economics. Yet the growth of Islamic financial
institutions are seen to have created two effects on the recent
development in Islamic economics that remain questionable as good academic
practice.
First, the Islamic financial institutions were at times politically moved
to use certain Shari'ah precepts while they functioned in imperfectly
Islamic environments at home and abroad. The motivation, if not the
emotion, was based on the need to mobilize resources of Muslim individuals
and nations according to the precepts of Shari'ah. It is known however,
that the outlets for mobilizing the resources of the Islamic community
through these financial institutions were not necessarily Islamic in
character. For instance, it has remained a bone of contention among some
Islamic economists, whether mark-up pricing (murabaha) in trade of any
kind, is legitimate profit or interest. It is also known that simply
charging a rate of mark-up lower than the average world rate of interest
(quoted by G7 countries), does not constitute a legitimate substitution
for the underlying interest rate premise. It is also known that
entrepreneurs in many Muslim countries have shirked profit-sharing
financial alternatives to interest-bearing ones. Interest transactions
remain unequivocally unlawful under Shari'ah.
Secondly, the emerging Islamic economists took stock of the fervour caused
by the establishment of Islamic financial institutions, and viewed the
economics of financial markets to be foremost in the formulation of
Islamic economic ideas. In this area we find a growing concentration of
Ph.D. thesis and scholarly papers on money, banking, investment, savings
and resource mobilization, and some consequential focus in the area of
development financing. International conferences and research bias
remained on these areas, to the extent that much of the research funds for
the study of Islamic economics today are flowing either from capital rich
countries or through endowments set up by grants from the capital rich
countries or their rich individual citizens. Thus, Islamic economists and
institutions became subservient to the research field of financing
resource mobilization of the Islamic individuals and countries in the face
of the Islamic commercial and financial developments that have taken place
during the last two decades.
To categorize the areas in which most emphasis has been placed by Islamic
economists, they are, Islamic finance, money and banking; financing
development and resource mobilization; theory and application of Shari'ah
in developing secondary capital market instruments; macroeconomic models
of Islamic economic systems, monetary and investment relationships;
Islamic economic history; and international Islamic economic co-operation.
The areas of Islamic microeconomics, growth and comparative systems are
given small but growing focus. In all of these areas, the bias remains
firmly fixed in the pursuit of either neoclassical or Keynesian
methodologies in Islamic economic analysis. In other words, Islamic
economists have continued to use existing economic models, logical
premises and occidental worldviews to address certain Islamic values and
institutional norms. No new demands on fresh economic reasoning are
therefore invoked to develop what may be claimed as a distinctive field of
Islamic economics. Islamic economics then remains simply mainstream
economics with value-judgement introduced into the analysis. This approach
is similar to social economics, institutionalism, or of recent days study
of socio-economics, all of which are value-laden economic analysis in the
neoclassical and Keynesian (post-Keynesian) mould.
There are sparing exceptions in Islamic socio-economic doctrines, where
deeper questions of economic epistemology are raised. Better works in this
area are by the sociologist, e.g. Shariati. On the other hand, the works
by Baqir as-Sadr have proven to be of a populist nature, invoking Islamic
economic thinking in comparative perspectives with the capitalist and
socialist systems. Islamic economics was subsequently seen to be equatable
to a middle way between the capitalist and socialist economic doctrines
with a good deal of state intervention. Some Islamic economists equated
the latter influence with Islamic welfare state.
FROM ISLAMIC ECONOMICS TO ISLAMIC POLITICAL ECONOMY
It is then
important to investigate whether Islamic economics can be logically
pursued within the existing methodologies and axiomatic bounds of
mainstream economics. Or must Islamic socio- economic analysis be
based on an altogether new epistemological premise?
According to the first of these pursuits in the area of Islamic
economics, it will be an incorrect view to treat Islamic economics
as Islamic political economy. The field of Islamic economics simply
constitutes the theoretical and empirical study of positive economic
phenonemon with the use of correcting policies and behavioural norms
prescribed by Islam. Islamic economic history can then be taken up
in this area to play an exogenous body of study, which at best,
conveys the historical ways in which the Islamic norms were
understood and implemented. Such an approach to the study of Islamic
economics necessitates no fresh demand on nor development of, the
epistemolgical foundations of morals, ethics and values that
essentially endogenize the Islamic system of socio- economic
reasoning. It is not sufficient for such endogenous premises of
values to be simply drawn from the Qur'an and Sunnah, and then be
subjected to rigorous scientific investigation. It is necessary as
well for such an intellectual inquiry to become universally
acceptable in some form to the scientific community and institutions
by its sheer analytical prowess. The ideas so discovered and
developed must then be capable of intellectual dissemination in the
classrooms, scientific fora and through national and international
institutions. This is the Islamic worldview that remains pervasive,
inexorable universally.
In this second approach to the study of Islamic socio-economic
doctrines, such a discipline must intellectually cease to be
classified as `economics'. It will be substantively replaced by the
idea of political economy. But here too, the idea of political
economy would be a singularly different one from that of classical,
neoclassical, Marxist and institutionalist persuasions. Included in
the last category is also the Keynesian idea of political economy.
The reason for this difference in substance of the terminology is
that Islamic political economy is essentially a study of the
endogenous role of ethico-economic relationships between polity and
the deep ecological system. Within this grand ecological system is
the subsystem of the market. But the Islamic market is neither
severed from the social and socio-political system nor is it overly
interrupted by institutional policing. Islam places high respect on
the market process, but necessitates its moral standing.
The polity of the Islamic socio-economic system is called Shura. The
Shura is constituted of decision-makers who are learned persons in
the tenets of Shari'ah on specific political, socio- economic and
scientific issues. These fields when viewed in the light of the
broadest application of Shari'ah, become of the nature of Deen
(divine code of life). The decision-makers in such Shuras come from
very decentralized areas of life with participatory democratic
privileges to form collective decisions. Such decisions are
colectively formed through voting (complete or partial social
consensus) in the Shura. The Shura formulates market friendly,
socially friendly policies for morally ethicizing such systems. Such
on-going interactions generate polity-market interrelationships,
with the market system responding to the policy regimes instituted
by the Shura on the basis of knowledge of Shari'ah on specific
issues (formation of Ahkam, or rules from fundamentals, Usul). The
power structure of polity-market interactions of an ethico-economic
type thus explained by the Islamic concept of political economy, is
aimed at developing integration through interactions between the
Shura and the market system in accordance with the precept of the
Qur'an and Sunnah.
The strength of these sources of knowledge in Islamic political
economy is based on the belief that human reason must comprehend
naturally the inevitablity and perptuation of truth in God's Oneness
in the order of things (Tawhid). The Precept of Oneness forms the
primordial foundation of Shari'ah. This guides the Shura in deriving
its knowledge from the premise of Shari'ah (Usul) and developing
necessary policy prescriptions on specific issues (Ahkam). A
knowledge-based process of transformation is then generated in the
socio-scientific thinkers in the Shura (i.e. among the Sharees), in
the institutions that such knowledge development influences, and in
the society at large that the above two integrate to transform. In
this knowledge-forming process, the Precept of Unicity of God as the
unifying worldview (weltanschauung) for understanding and
inculcating truth through integrating interrelationships between God
(Shari'ah), man (socio- economic order = Istihsan or Muamalat) and
nature (scientific order, Khalq).
One then notes carefully, that the concept of Shura as consultation,
now taken up as interactions leading to integration (=social
consensus) in aall issues before it, is a universal property of
systems and processes. It is not simply limited to the political
order. It takes up polity-market (better as deep ecological
interrelations) interactions. Such interactions are also pervasive
in all enterprises and institutions, wherever decision making exists
in the small and in the large. Shura thus assumes the intrinsic
property of a universal process. Such a worldview of the universal
and infallible character Shura is essentially the Qur'anic idea of
creative evolution combined by the attributes of just balance, just
purpose, certainty, felicity and reorigination.
|
ISLAMIC POLITICAL ECONOMY DEFINED: A COMPARATIVE STUDY
In summary then, Islamic political economy is the study of
interactive relationships between polity (Shura) and the ecological
order (with market subsystem). These interactions are made to
develop human comprehension, social receptivity and
institutionalization of Shari'ah in the conduct of life. Such a
worldview of ethico-economic relations is developed through the
primacy of the Oneness of God as substantively understood in the
socio-scientific order. Thus the Shura as a process perpetuates its
existence in the midst of this unifying worldview. It is neither the
objective nor the strength of Shura to use forced institutional
intervention, or for that, to permit irresponsible market pursuits.
Values thus become the endogenous engines of Islamic transformation
in such an interactive and integrative polity-market system.
|
THE PRINCIPLES OF ISLAMIC POLITICAL ECONOMY
It is commonly
agreed upon by all sections of Islamic thinkers, that one of the
prime attributes of God (hence of the Unity Precept) is justice (Adl).
The concept of justice is expressed in the Qur'an and Sunnah in
terms of the broadly comprehensive concept of balance. In the
limited sense of socio- economics, just balance becomes distributive
justice. But since the precints of political economy encompass both
society, economy and deep ecology, the narrower concept of
distributive equity is replaced by the idea of social justice in the
Islamic political economy. Besides, there being no difference
between the antecedentalist and consequentialist phases of social
justice in the sense of continuity between the epistemic and ontic,
so the ideas of social justice and distributive justice must remain
inseparable in Islamic political economy. Hence, the Unity Precept,
which must be the principal premise of knowledge in Islamic
political economy, must fully define the laws governing social
justice in this comprehensive sense.
The Qur'an and Sunnah also emphasize the central need for guarantee
and protection of property rights or entitlement. Thus we find the
high value of market processes in Islamic political economy and the
non-coercive power of Shura. The Shura acts principally as a
knowledge-forming agency for the guidance of society in accordance
with Shari'ah, and brings socially unfriendly consequence under
control through its supportive agencies, such as Al-Hisbah (social
regulatory body for markets). Besides, because of the unifying
concept of social justice in Islamic political economy, the concept
of property rights must also invoke guarantee and protection of all
forms of property rights concerning human possession and welfare.
The role of work and productivity must be considered as a subset of
the principle of entitlement (property rights) (Haq al- Mal). Such a
sub-principle cannot be raised to the level of a full- fledged
principle for reasons that social productivity and entitlement must
mean caring and protection of the needy, the weak, the old, the
young and the underprivileged. It is also found, that an Islamic
economy may have a significant profit-sharing and cooperative
sector. In this case, the concept of work is not understood in terms
of wage-payments alone; nor is the contribution of output
interpreted either as average or marginal productivity, as in the
neoclassical sense. However, in any case, since this aspect of
social justice and subsequently, universal formation and protection
of property, cannot be realized in the absence of productive work
and capital formation, therefore, the sub-principle of work and
productivity is an implied subset of the principle of entitlement.
We have thus established the minimal set of three principles of
Islamic political economy, namely, first, the Unity Precept of God (Tawhid
which is supported by the Sunnah of Prophet Muhammad); secondly, the
principle of social justice; thirdly, the principle of entitlement
(or property rights, of which is a sub-principle of work and
productivity). To this minimal set can be added other sub-
principles, such as, prayers, responsible behaviour, generosity,
kindness (Ehsan), duties to God (Hablum-Min- Allah), duties to man (Hablum-Min-Annas),
etc. But these attributes are obviously included in the relationship
of Tawhid with the formation of laws (Shari'ah) governing both
social justice and entitlement. It is seen as well that the three
principles circularly interrelate with each other.
|
THE PRINCIPAL INSTRUMENTS OF ISLAMIC POLITICAL ECONOMY
Next, we will
examine the field of instruments of Islamic political economy based
on and serving the above fundamental principles. All Islamic
economists agree that the abolition of interest (Riba) is a
mandatory injunction of the Qur'an. The argument is both of a moral
and economic nature. The Qur'an points to interest, irrespective of
its magnitude, as an undue charge and a take by the rich from the
poor. There is however, considerable debate among the Islamic
learneds (Fuqaha) as to what constitutes interest in all its forms
-- physical exchange of items and trade in monetary assets.
The mention of profit-sharing under economic cooperation amongst all
forms of participants in investment and production is implicit in
the Qur'an, but is directly invoked in the Sunnah. This instrument
is known as either Mudarabah (profit-sharing with cooperation) or
Musharakah (equity participation). The institution of profit-sharing
under economic cooperation at all levels of the Islamic political
economy, is the principal alternative for replacing interest-bearing
transactions. Hence, since abolition of Riba is a fundamental
condition for attaining social and economic welfare and justice, the
institution of Mudarabah and Musharakah must be equally important
instruments for making the elimination of Riba effective.
The Qur'an has placed the highest importance along with prayers, on
the duty of paying wealth tax (Zakat) by the wealthy for the
rehabilitation of the needy. Zakat revenues are to be collected and
disbursed in an organized way. In early era of Islam this method of
managing Zakat funds was known as Bait al-Mal, the Public Treasury.
Zakat marginalizes other forms of direct taxes in the Islamic
political economy, for the Government comes to assume minimal
function in such a system, while the responsibility to generate
economic activity is predominantly passed on to the market economy
with a Shuratic guidance.
Zakat along with elimination of Riba and its replacement by
Mudarabah/Musharakah, constitutes a form of enhanced spending in the
economy. The absence of interest-bearing on personal loans along
with the gift of Zakat, generates a form of grants economy, with
their impetus on investment and spending through the attributes of
human solidarity and goodwill.
Finally, the Qur'an is emphatic on the elimination of economic waste
through ostentatious consumption and wasteful production (Israf).
Elimination of Israf is seen to logically link up with the
efficiency of Mudarabah, which then results in an impetus to
eliminate Riba. Riba itself is considered as a form of Israf in the
Islamic sense. But to the extent that Zakat disbursement is a
function of relative poverty and a relative concept of need, over
and above absolute poverty levels, and depends on population size in
these brackets, therefore, this disbursement would increase either
by an increase in national incomes or by a reduction of the target
population size. Hence, an effective reduction of waste followed by
its consequential relationship with Mudarabah, would mobilize
capital into productive investments. This will have an enhancing
effect on Zakat to combat poverty and generate more distribution.
We have now established the minimal number of instruments needed for
the Islamic political economy. These are, abolition of Riba,
institutions of Mudarabah/Musharakah; the institution of wealth tax,
Zakah; and the elimination of waste, Israf. On top of these other
instruments can be built (e.g. Murabaha, Bay Muajjal, Unit Trust
etc.). But the more detailed list of instruments does not turn out
to be independent of the minimal core stated here.
For example, mark-up in foreign trade financing (Murabaha), rental (Ijara),
leasing (Ba'y Muajjal), interest-free loans (Qard- e-Hassanah),
endowments (Waqf), a range of Shari'ah prescribed secondary market
instruments, etc., can be added to the minimal list of instruments.
But these would simply belong to a category of Mudarabah/Musharakah
instruments. Besides, the latter categories being derivatives of the
minimal set, have not been mentioned either in the Qur'an or the
Sunnah. Hence, the latter list of instruments give details rather
than principality. They are also subject to options, unlike the
instruments of the minimal set, which form the principal category.
|
INTERACTIONS BETWEEN THE PRINCIPLES AND INSTRUMENTS
It can now be
seen how these instruments link up with the principles of Islamic
political economy and vice-versa. The universal application of
Shari'ah (thus, Tawhid) inculcates social responsibility to
establish justice and property rights amongst all. In order to
realize this social objective, the instruments must be activated.
This direction of relationship establishes the interactive
realization in knowledge formation in Islamic political economy.
Conversely, starting from the premise of instruments, the activation
of socio-economic activity in conjunction with the exercise of the
instruments, leads to better comprehension of Shari'ah through the
socio-economic efficacy that it imparts through the prescribed
instruments. This forms the cycle of knowledge formation. Hence, the
interactions between the principles and instruments in the Shura
along with the responses from the socio-economic variables (most
importantly the spending variable and its socio-economic effects)
that are affected by such knowledge formation, establishes
circularity as the basis of evolution of the Islamic political
economy on the basis of knowledge formation.
The anthropic power of the Shuratic model is realized in its real
world application and in the heuristic form of institutional
behaviour. Its general features only and not the predictive form,
can be modelled mathematically by simulation methods.
|
|
|